Proportional representation

Proportional representation (PR), sometimes referred to as full representation, is a class of voting system aimed at securing a close match between the percentage of votes that groups of candidates obtain in elections, and the percentage of seats they receive (e.g., in legislative assemblies).

PR is often contrasted to plurality voting systems, such as those commonly used in the United States and (much of) the United Kingdom, where disproportional seat distribution results from the division of voters into multiple electoral districts, especially "winner takes all" plurality ("first-past-the-post" or FPTP) districts.

Contents

Methods of proportional representation

Proportional representation allows all voters a degree of influence on the political process. Proportional systems typically use political parties as the measure of representation. For example, a party that receives 15% of the votes under such a system receives 15% of the seats.[1] By contrast, the established parties in current US and UK elections can, and most often do, win control of the parliament with support from as little as 20-25% of eligible voters, at the cost of smaller parties.[2]

Different methods of proportional representation achieve either greater proportionality or a more determinate outcome.[3]

Party-list proportional representation is one approach, in which the above-mentioned groups correspond directly with candidate lists from political parties. The open list form allows the voter to influence the election of individual candidates within a party list. The closed list approach does not. Another variation is the single transferable vote (STV), which does not depend on political parties (and where the "measure of grouping" is entirely left up to the voters.) Elections for the Australian Senate use what is referred to as above-the-line voting where candidates for each party are grouped on the ballot, allowing the voter for the group or for a candidate.

Other variations include single non-transferable vote (SNTV), cumulative voting and limited bloc voting (LBV), all of which offer a form of semi-proportional representation (SPR).

The emphasis on political parties may reduce PR's effectiveness. Political parties' influence is declining in countries such as the U.S., which in 2004 saw 24% of voters declaring themselves to be independent. In such polities, an alternative such as #loser delegation can achieve full representation in a different way.

Party list system in a multi-member constituency

The parties each list their candidates according to that party's determination of priorities. In closed list systems, voters vote for a list, not a candidate. Each party is allocated seats in proportion to the number of votes it receives, using the party-determined ranking order. In an open list, voters may vote, depending on the model, for one person, or for two, or indicate their order of preference within the list.

Additional-member system, mixed-member system

Main articles: Additional Member Systems - mixed member proportional representation and parallel voting; alternative vote and alternative vote top-up

Mixed election systems combine a proportional system and a single seat district system, attempting to achieve some of the positive features of each. Mixed systems are often helpful in countries with large populations, since they balance local and national concerns. They are used in nations with diverse geographic, social, cultural and economic issues, including Bolivia, Germany, Lesotho, Mexico and the United Kingdom.

Single transferable vote in a multi-member constituency

This system uses preferential voting.

Each constituency elects two or more representatives per electorate. Consequently the constituency is proportionally larger than single member constituencies that produce the same number of representatives. Parties tend to offer as many candidates as they optimistically could expect to win: major parties nominate more than minor parties. Voters allocate "votes" to their preferred ranking for some or all candidates. A successful candidate must achieve a quota, which is the number of votes cast divided by the number of candidates to be elected plus one; i.e. in a nine member constituency the quota would be (the number of votes divided by 10) +1. Only in a few cases is this achieved at the first count. For the second count, if a candidate wins election her/his surplus vote (in excess of the quota) is transferred to the voters' second choices; otherwise, the least popular candidate is eliminated and those votes are redistributed according to the second preference shown on them. If more than one candidate cannot get enough votes after the transfer of votes of the least popular candidate, that candidate is also eliminated (as they would be eliminated on the next round anyway.)

The process repeats until all seats are filled either when the required number of candidates achieve the quota or until the number of remaining candidates matches the number of remaining seats. Although the counting process is complicated, voting is clear and most voters get at least one of their preferences elected.

All deputies are answerable directly to their local constituents. Some political scientists argue that STV is more properly classified as 'semi-proportional' as there is no assurance of a proportional result at a national level. Indeed, many advocates of STV argue that preventing nationwide proportionality is one of the primary goals of the system, to avoid the perceived risks of a fragmented legislature.

Loser delegation in a single-member constituency

"Loser delegation" voting can produce still greater representation in legislatures. This system allows losing candidates to delegate the votes they receive to the winning candidate in their own or in another district without regard to party. Delegated votes don't affect who enters the legislature, but they do affect subsequent legislative votes. Each representative's legislative votes are weighted by the sum of the direct and delegated votes they received. Delegated voting can be combined with first-past-the-post, instant-runoff, or other counting rules that determine the winning candidate.

For example, consider a district where Sarah receives 45% of the votes, while Barack takes 40%, leaving Joe with the remaining 15%. Under traditional first-past-the-post rules, Sarah wins, leaving 55% of the voters without representation. In instant run-off, if 80% of Joe's voters picked Barack as their second choice, he would win in the second round, with 52% of the final total to Sarah's 48%, bringing second-choice representation to 7% of the voters, while leaving Sarah's voters without a voice.

Under loser delegation in the instant-runoff case, Barack joins the legislature, while Sarah can sign her votes over to Mitt, who won with 56% in a nearby district. Now those who voted for Sarah have about as much voice in legislation (via Mitt) as Barack's voters; nobody is left unrepresented. Barack effectively casts 52 votes, Mitt casts 56 + 48 or 101, and also-moderate Blanche casts 58 (her winning percentage in a third district.) Of course, the losers in Mitt and Blanche's districts also get to delegate their votes, so Barack could conceivably end up casting 52 + 44 + 42 or 138 votes.

However, combining proxy with first-past-the-post may be a better choice because that way Joe can choose to give his votes to Blanche instead of seeing them handed to Barack following the runoff. Now Sarah casts 45 as her district's representative, Barack delegates his 40 to Nancy to add to her 70, Mitt stays at 56, and Blanche casts 58 + 15 or 73.

History

The schoolmaster Thomas Wright Hill is credited as inventor of the single transferable vote, whose use he described in 1821 for application in elections at his school. The method, which guarantees proportional representation, was introduced in 1840 by his son Rowland Hill into the public election for the Adelaide City Council. Unlike several later systems, this did not allow for party-list proportional representation.

Single Transferable Vote was first used in Denmark in 1857, making STV the oldest PR system, but the system used there never really spread. STV was re-invented (apparently independently) in the UK, but the British parliament rejected it.

A party-list proportional representation system was first devised and described in 1878 by Victor D'Hondt of Belgium. The procedure, known as the D'Hondt method, is still widely used. Victor Considérant, a utopian socialist, devised a similar system in an 1892 book. Some Swiss cantons (beginning with Ticino in 1890) preceded Belgium which was the first to adopt list-PR in 1900 for its national parliament. Many European countries adopted similar systems during or after World War I.

STV was used in Tasmania in 1907. In the last Irish elections to the UK Parliament in 1919, STV was used in the University of Dublin constituency; two Independent Unionists were elected. STV has been in use since Irish independence. A mainly centrist party, Fianna Fáil, typically receives 30%-50% of the vote while opposition parties, traditionally the centre-right Fine Gael and the centre-left Labour Party, are comparatively weak. This has led to a series of coalition governments; there has not been a single-party government since 1989.

PR is used by more nations than the plurality voting system, and it dominates Europe, including Germany, most of northern and eastern Europe, and for European Parliament elections. France adopted PR at the end of World War II, discarding it in 1958. In 1986 it was used for parliament elections.

While FPTP is commonly found in countries based on the British parliamentary system, and in Westminster elections in the United Kingdom, the Scottish Parliament and the Welsh National Assembly use a form of PR known as the mixed member system, after New Zealand adopted it in 1993. Five Canadian provinces—British Columbia, Ontario, Quebec, Prince Edward Island and New Brunswick— are debating whether to abolish FPTP.

PR has some history in the United States. Many cities, including New York City, once used it to break up the Democratic Party city councils monopolies on elective office. Cincinnati, Ohio, adopted PR in 1925 to get rid of a Republican Party party machine, but the Republicans returned the city to FPTP in 1957. From 1870 to 1980, Illinois used a semi-proportional cumulative voting system to elect its State House of Representatives. Each district across the state elected both Republicans and Democrats year-after-year. Cambridge, Massachusetts and Peoria, Illinois continue to use PR. San Francisco had city-wide elections where people would cast votes for five or six candidates simultaneously, delivering some of the benefits of proportional representation.

In his essay, Overcoming Practical Difficulties in Creating a World Parliamentary Assembly, Joseph E. Schwartzberg proposes the use of proportional representation in the United Nations Parliamentary Assembly in order to prevent, for instance, lower castes of Indians from being excluded.[4]

Partial proportionality

Some nations with proportional elections, like Israel and the Netherlands, have one electoral district only: the entire nation, and the entire pie is cut up according to the entire outcome. Most nations have district systems in place where more than one person is elected per district. The constituency or district magnitude (DM) of a system is therefore measured by the number of seats per constituency. The greater the number of seats in a constituency, the more proportional the outcome will be. PR applied to a single-member district (SMD) is by necessity majoritarian. If the constituency is in a jurisdiction using list PR in its multimember districts (MMDs) the winning candidate simply needs a plurality, otherwise called a simple or relative majority, of the vote to win, so that the election in the SMD is by first-past-the-post. If the constituency is in a jurisdiction using PR-STV in its MMDs, an absolute majority of 50% plus 1 will likely be the minimum required for victory (depending on which quota is used) so that the election in the SMD is by the alternative vote. Four elected officials per district delivers a threshold of 20% (1/M+1) to gain a single seat. However, constituency borders can still be gerrymandered to reduce proportionality. This may be achieved by creating "majority-minority" constituencies - constituencies in which the majority is formed by a group of voters that are in the minority at a higher level. Proportional representation with the entire nation electing the single body cannot be gerrymandered.

Multimember districts do not necessarily ensure that an electoral system will be proportional. The bloc vote can result in "super-majoritarian" results in which geographical variations can create majority-minority districts that become subsumed into the larger districts. Also, a party that does not run enough people to fill all the seats it wins may be given those unfilled seats. This is termed an underhang.

Some nations, with either exclusively proportional representation or—as is the case with Germany—additional member systems, require a party list to achieve an election threshold—a set minimum percentage of votes to receive any seats. Typically, this lower limit is between two and five percent of the number of votes cast. Parties who do not reach that support are not represented in parliament, making majorities, coalitions and thus governments easier to achieve. Proponents of election thresholds argue that they discourage fragmentation, disproportionate power, or extremist parties. Opponents of thresholds argue that they unfairly redirect support from minor parties, giving parties which cross the threshold disproportionate numbers of seats and creating the possibility that a party or coalition will assume control of the legislature without gaining a majority of votes.

The most common way of measuring proportionality is the Gallagher Index.

Center based proportional and multi-party systems

Election systems based on proportional representation tend to favor a multi-party result which demands a coalition to form a government supported by a majority of the voters or elected candidates. If the election system as well as the mechanisms for forming a governing coalition also tend to support the existence of a centrist party, the resulting over-all system is often defined as a "center-based proportional representation multi-party system". Election systems which tend to result in so-called two-block (many parties forming coalitions, blocks, but with no party, or "block", in the "center") systems are not seen as "center-based" but multi-party variations of two-party (two-block) systems.

The undesirable "extreme" of a "Center Based" system (like in Condorcet method) might be seen as a party system where the "center" has an unproportional and undesirable strong position in the formation of any governing coalition.

List of countries using proportional representation

This is a list of countries using proportional representation at national level.

Country Type
 Algeria Party list
 Angola Party list
 Australia For Senate only, Single Transferable Vote
 Austria Party list
 Argentina Party list
 Aruba Party list
 Belgium Party list
 Bolivia Mixed Member Majoritarian
 Brazil Party list
 Bulgaria Party list
 Burkina Faso Party list
 Burundi Party list
 Cambodia Party list
 Cape Verde Party list
 Colombia Party list
 Costa Rica Party list
 Croatia Party list
 Cyprus Party list
 Czech Republic Party list
 Democratic Republic of the Congo Mixed member proportional
 Denmark Party list
 Dominican Republic Party list
 Equatorial Guinea Party list
 Estonia Party list
 Finland Party list
 Germany Mixed member proportional
 Greece Party list (with plurality bonus)
 Guinea-Bissau Party list
 Guyana Party list
 Hungary Mixed Member Majoritarian
 Iceland Party list
 India For Upper House (Rajya Sabha) only, Single Transferable Vote by State Legislatures
 Indonesia Party list
 Iraq Party list
 Ireland Single Transferable Vote
 Israel Party list
 Italy Party list (with plurality bonus for coalitions)
 Japan Mixed Member Majoritarian
 Latvia Party list
 Lesotho Mixed Member Majoritarian
 Liberia Party list
 Liechtenstein Party list
 Luxembourg Party list
 Malta Single Transferable Vote
 Mexico Mixed Member Majoritarian
 Moldova Party list
 New Zealand Mixed Member Proportional
 Namibia Party list
 Netherlands Party list
 Netherlands Antilles Party list
 New Caledonia Party list
 Nicaragua Party list
 Northern Ireland Single Transferable Vote (for regional assembly only)
 Norway Party list
 Paraguay Party list
 Peru Party list
 Poland Party list
 Portugal Party list
 Romania Party list
 Russia Party list
 San Marino Party list
 Sao Tome and Principe Party list
 Scotland Additional Member System (for national assembly only)
 Slovakia Party list
 Slovenia Party list
 South Africa Party list
 South Korea Party list
 Spain Party list
 Sri Lanka Party list
 Suriname Party list
 Sweden Party list
 Switzerland Party list
 Taiwan Mixed Member Majoritarian
 Thailand Mixed Member Majoritarian
 Turkey Party list
 Ukraine Party list
 Uruguay Party list
 Venezuela Party list
 Wales Additional Member System (for national assembly only)
 Wallis and Futuna Party list

Further reading

Books

Journals

News

See also

Notes

  1. Kolesar, Robert J. (1996-04-20). "Communism, Race, and the Defeat of Proportional Representation in Cold War America". Massachusetts: Mount Holyoke College. http://www.mtholyoke.edu/acad/polit/damy/articles/kolesar.htm. Retrieved 2010-05-12. 
  2. McDonald, Dr. Michael. "United States Election Project > Voter Turnout". Fairfax, VA: George Mason University. http://elections.gmu.edu/Turnout.html. Retrieved 2010-05-12. 
  3. "Polling systems across the world and how they work - Scotsman.com News". News.scotsman.com. http://news.scotsman.com/politics/Polling-systems-across-the-world.6038354.jp. Retrieved 2010-05-08. 
  4. Schwartzberg, Joseph E. (September 2002). "Creating a World Parliamentary Assembly". Washington, DC: World Federalist Institute. http://globalsolutions.org/node/1071. Retrieved 12 May 2010. 

External links